Главная | Обратная связь | Поможем написать вашу работу!
МегаЛекции

Introduction   9. 10   Smelser/Swedberg




Introduction      9

 

not only by economic interest but also by tradition and emotions; furthermore, it is always oriented to some actor(s).

If one disregards single actions, Weber says, and instead focuses on empirical uniformities, it is pos­sible to distinguish three different types: those in­spired by " convention, " by " custom" (including " habit" ), and by " interest" ([1922] 1978, 29-36). Most uniform types of action presumably consist of a mixture of all three. Actions that are " deter­mined by interest" are defined by Weber as instru­mental in nature and oriented to identical expecta­tions. An example would be the modern market, where each actor is instrumentally rational and counts on everybody else to be so as well.

Weber emphasized that interests are always sub­jectively perceived; no " objective" interests exist beyond the individual actor. In a typical sentence Weber speaks of " [the] interests of the actors as they themselves are aware of them" ([1922] 1978, 30). He also notes that when several individuals behave in an instrumental manner in relation to their individual interests, the typical result is col­lective patterns of behavior that are considerably more stable than those driven by norms imposed by an authority. It is, for example, very difficult to make people do something economic that goes against the individual's interest.

A sketch of Weber's economic sociology in Economy and Society yields the following main points. Economic actions of two actors who are oriented to one another constitute an economic relationship. These relationships can take various expressions, including conflict, competition, and power. If two or more actors are held together by a sense of belonging, their relationship is " com­munal"; and if they are held together by interest, " associative" (Weber [1922] 1978, 38-43). Eco­nomic relationships (as all social relationships) can also be open or closed. Property represents a spe­cial form of closed economic relationship.

Economic organizations constitute another im­portant form of closed economic relationships. Some of these organizations are purely economic, while others have some subordinate economic goals or have as their main task the regulation of economic affairs. A trade union is an example. Weber attaches great importance to the role in cap­italism of the firm, which he sees as the locus of en­trepreneurial activity and as a revolutionary force.

A market, like many other economic phenome­na, is centered around a conflict of interests—in this case between sellers and buyers (Weber [1922] 1978, 635^Ј0). A market involves both exchange


 

10   Smelser/Swedberg

 

and competition. Competitors must first fight out who will be the final seller and the final buyer (" competition struggle" ); and only when this struggle has been settled is the scene set for the ex­change itself (" exchange struggle" ). Only rational capitalism is centered around the modern type of market (Weber [1922] 1978, 164-66). In so- called political capitalism the key to profit making is rather the state or the political power that grants some favor, supplies protection, or the like. Tradi­tional commercial capitalism consists of small-scale trading, in money or merchandise. Rational capi­talism has emerged only in the West.

Emile Durkheim

As compared to Weber, Emile Durkheim (1858- 1917) knew less economics, wrote less about economic topics, and in general made less of a contri­bution to economic sociology (e. g., Steiner 2004). While none of his major studies can be termed a work in economic sociology, all of them nonethe­less touch on economic topics (see also Durkheim [1950] 1983). Durkheim also strongly supported the project of developing a sociologie economique by encouraging some of his students to specialize in this area and by routinely including a section on economic sociology in his journal L'annйe soci­ologique. At one point he gave the following defi­nition of economic sociology:

Finally there are the economic institutions: institu­tions relating to the production of wealth (serfdom, tenant farming, corporate organization, production in factories, in mills, at home, and so on), institutions re­lating to exchange (commercial organization, mar­kets, stock exchanges, and so on), institutions relating to distribution (rent, interest, salaries, and so on). They form the subject matter of economic sociology. (Durkheim [1909] 1978b, 80)

Durkheim's first major work, The Division of Labor in Society (1893), has most direct relevance for economic sociology. Its core consists of the ar­gument that social structure changes as society de­velops from its undifferentiated state, in primor­dial times, to a stage characterized by a complex division of labor, in modern times. Economists, Durkheim notes, view the division of labor exclu­sively as an economic phenomenon, and its gains in terms of efficiency. What he added was a socio­logical dimension of the division of labor—how it helps to integrate society by coordinating special­ized activities.

As part of society's evolution to a more ad­vanced division of labor, the legal system changes.

 

From being predominantly repressive in nature, and having its center in penal law, it now becomes restitutive and has its center in contractual law. In discussing the contract, Durkheim also described as an illusion the belief, held by Herbert Spencer, that a society can function if all individuals simply follow their private interests and contract accord­ingly (Durkheim [1893] 1984, 152). Spencer also misunderstood the very nature of the contractual relationship. A contract does not work in situations where self-interest rules supreme, but only where there is a moral or regulative element. " The con­tract is not sufficient by itself, but is only possible because of the regulation of contracts, which is so­cial in origin" (Durkheim [1893] 1984, 162).

A major concern in The Division of Labor in Society is that the recent economic advances in France may destroy society by letting loose indi­vidual greed to erode its moral fiber. This prob­lematic is often cast in terms of the private versus the general interest, as when Durkheim notes that " subordination of the particular to the general in­terest is the very well-spring of all moral activity" ([1893] 1984, xliii). Unless the state or some other agency that articulates the general interest steps in to regulate economic life, the result will be " economic anomie, " a topic that Durkheim dis­cusses in Suicide ([1897] 1951, 246ffi, 259). Peo­ple need rules and norms in their economic life, and they react negatively to anarchic situations.

In many of Durkheim's works, one finds a sharp critique of economists; and it was Durkheim's con­viction in general that if economics was ever to be­come scientific, it would have to become a branch of sociology. He attacked the idea of homo economicus on the ground that it is impossible to sep­arate out the economic element and disregard the rest of social life ([1888] 1978a, 49-50). The point is not that economists used an analytical or abstract approach, Durkheim emphasized, but that they had selected the wrong abstractions (1887, 39). Durkheim also attacked the nonempirical tenden­cy of economics and the idea that one can figure out how the economy works through " a simple logical analysis" ([1895] 1964, 24). Durkheim re­ferred to this as " the ideological tendency of eco­nomics" ([1895] 1964, 25).

Durkheim's recipe for a harmonious industrial society is as follows: each industry should be orga­nized into a number of corporations, in which the individuals will thrive because of the solidarity and warmth that comes from being a member of a group ([18931 1984, Iii). He was well aware of the rule that interest plays in economic life, and in The


 

Elementary Forms of Religious Life he stresses that " the principal incentive to economic activity has always been the private interest" ([1912] 1965, This does not mean that economic life is purely self-interested and devoid of morality: " We remain [in our economic affairs] in relation with others; the habits, ideas and tendencies which education has impressed upon us and which ordinarily preside de over our relations can never be totally absent” (390). But even if this is the case, the social element has another source other than the economy and will eventually be worn down if not renewed.

Georg Simmel

Simmel's works typically lack references to economics as such. Simmel (1858-1918), like Durkheim,  usually viewed economic phenomena within some larger, noneconomic setting. Nonetheless, his work still has relevance for economic sociology.

Much of Simmel's most important study, Soziologie (1908), focuses on the analysis of interests. He suggested what a sociological interest analysis: should look like and why it is indispensable to sociology. Two of his general propositions are that interests drive people to form social relations, and that it is only through these social relations that interests can be expressed:

Sociation is the form (realized in innumerable differ­ent ways) in which individuals grow together into a  unity and within which their interests are realized. And it is on the basis of their interests—sensuous or. deal, momentary or lasting, conscious or uncon­scious, causal or teleological—that individuals form such units. (Simmel [1908] 1971, 24)

Another key proposition is that economic interests, like other interests, can take a number of different social expressions (26).

Soziolojyie also contains a number of suggestive analyses of economic phenomena, among them competition. In a chapter on the role of the number of actors in social life, Simmel suggests that competition can take die form of tertius gaudens " lie third who benefits" ). In this situation, which involves three actors, actor A turns to advantage the fact that actors B and C are competing for A's favor—to buy something, to sell something, or the like. Competition is consequently not seen as something that only concerns the competitors (actor B and C); it is in addition related to actor A, the target of the competition. Simmel also distinguishes competition from conflict.  While a conflict typically means a confrontation between two ac-

 

 

Поделиться:





Воспользуйтесь поиском по сайту:



©2015 - 2024 megalektsii.ru Все авторские права принадлежат авторам лекционных материалов. Обратная связь с нами...